Credit Market Contagion

Credit Market Contagion
Turkish lira banknotes are pictured at a currency exchange office in Istanbul, Turkey August 13, 2018. (Reuters/Murad Sezer)
Dan Oliver
9/6/2018
Updated:
9/7/2018

To understand the routs in Turkey, Argentina, and other emerging markets, one needs to understand the anatomy of a credit bubble. They are all the same, although the companies and countries caught up in them are different.

Credit conflagrations are normally ignited by a small, wrong-footed speculator. Those with the thinnest capital have the most to win and the least to lose by levering up marginal asset as a bubble drives interest rates lower.

Once the cycle turns, rising rates tip over these small players first. Sometimes, their failure brings the system down immediately, if it is big enough to take down their lenders. Other times, they are merely the first to drown in the incoming tide.

The first panic of the United States came, for example, when Alexander Hamilton’s protege, William Duer, levered up his purchase of federal bonds with margin loans from state banks. When rates rose, Duer’s failure took down his lenders as well, igniting the panic of 1792.

In the panic of 1837, New Orleans cotton broker Hermann Briggs’s collapse brought down its New York correspondent banks, and the rest of the money market forthwith. In 1857, the failure of the Ohio Life Insurance and Trust Co. popped the railroad bubble. In 1907, it was Otto Heinze’s failed corner of the United Copper Co. that brought down his brokerage firm, its banks, and ignited the panic of that year. Some speculate that the Hatry fraud in London sparked the 1929 panic.

The “new economics” of Keynes argued that the state should bail out these speculators and those that aid and abet them to prevent the bubbles from popping: “Recessions are now considered to be fundamentally preventable, like airplane crashes and unlike hurricanes,” boasted economist Arthur Okun in 1970.

Operating on Irving Fisher’s theory that the Federal Reserve should impose price stability, the Fed raised rates in the late 1960s to control rising asset prices. Instead of a new equilibrium, the Fed got the Penn Central collapse, which threatened widespread panic. Peter L. Bernstein cautioned at the time:

“With all the narrow escapes we have had with railroads, airlines, and brokerage firms during 1970 [i.e., capital-intensive industries], it is to be hoped that the monetary authorities keep in mind that policies designed to fit in with overall public policy with respect to the economy as a whole can ricochet dangerously onto the quality of the assets of the institutions that create and hold the nation’s monetary assets.”

The Federal Reserve got the message, printed the money to bail out the banks, the currency depreciated, and inflation soared. The Fed tried to instill discipline a second time, raising rates throughout 1973 until the Franklin National Bank collapsed in late 1974. Down went rates again to prevent contagion. The Fed did it again, raising rates to end the inflation of the 1970s—Mexico and the rest of Latin America defaulted, which would have taken down America’s largest banks if the IMF and World Bank hadn’t intervened.

The pattern continued: Greenspan bailed out the market in 1987 after the portfolio insurance scam burst, then again for the Savings & Loan crisis, the Long Term Capital Management failure, the Asian contagion, and the internet bubble.

Then came Bernanke’s turn. The Federal Reserve began raising interest rates in June of 2004 to “stabilize” housing prices. The first sign something wasn’t right in the financial industry was the May 4, 2007 failure of Dillon Read, an internal UBS hedge fund that had invested heavily in subprime mortgages. With losses totaling only $125 million, the failure barely registered in the financial press.

The Marriner S. Eccles Federal Reserve Board building in Washington on July 14, 2016. (Benjamin Chasteen/Epoch Times)
The Marriner S. Eccles Federal Reserve Board building in Washington on July 14, 2016. (Benjamin Chasteen/Epoch Times)

In mid-June, two internal hedge funds at Bear Stearns required an injection of $3.2 billion to meet margin calls. The next month, a fund within IKB, a small German bank, found it couldn’t roll its asset-backed commercial paper—the parent bank lacked the resources to bail it out, prompting a 3.5 billion euro rescue from other banks. Spooked investors began dumping asset-backed commercial paper, the market for which shrank by a third in the second half of 2007.

In the nineteenth century, these failures would have led swiftly to a thorough market cleansing. By August, however, the European Central Bank (ECB) and the Fed were injecting funds into the overnight funds market and slashing interest rates, the Keynesian prescription.

The market soared, peaking in October of 2007. The Lehman panic was coming anyway—all they did was delay it by a year and make it worse. When the panic arrived, the Fed rolled out the policy it has pursued since 1921: it printed on a massive scale. Gold ran from $700 to $1,900, measuring the devaluation of the dollar.

The Current Emerging Market Bust

The Fed began raising rates in 2015 to constrain various asset bubbles, as it has throughout its history. It is an axiom of Austrian theory, confirmed by history, that rising interest rates pop credit bubbles—the current one will be no exception.

It looks like this time, as with the Latin American crisis of the 1980s and the Asian crisis of 1997, the culprit may be second-world countries, most notably Turkey. The problem is not just that Turkey has a lot of debt; the problem is that the debt is denominated in dollars and euros.

This means that the debt becomes more onerous as the local currency collapses. To illustrate, the lira has lost half its value against the dollar in the past year, meaning that dollar debts in local terms have suddenly doubled in size: They are unpayable.

Many of these dollar-denominated corporate debts are owed to Turkish banks, which, thus, feel the effects of the devaluation first. The Turkish lira has moved from 3.8 to the dollar at the beginning of the year to 7.0 in late August.

Goldman Sachs estimates Turkish bank capital will be completely exhausted when it hits 7.1, terminating the flow of credit, and accelerating the economic crash. How, then, will Turkey pay the $429 billion it owes to foreigners ($224 billion of which is held by international banks)?

Charles Gave of GaveKal noted, “When it comes to major defaults in Turkey, it takes little imagination to predict new banking turmoil in Europe.”

Most market commentators are as yet unconcerned, pointing out, for example, that Spanish banks have 229 billion euros in shareholder equity and only 74 billion euros in exposure to Turkey (already shaky Italian banks have 16 billion euros of exposure and French banks 31 billion euros).

Such analysis mistakes Turkey as an idiosyncratic problem as opposed to a symptom of a cracking global credit bubble. What will happen to Spain’s own domestic asset values as rates rise? What will happen to European sovereign debt markets, the reserve base of European banks, when Erdogan unleashes a flood of Turkish and Syrian migrants onto European shores?

Already the contagion is spreading.

Argentina’s currency is in free-fall, with the dollar gaining 130 percent in a year. Argentina owes $250 billion to foreign creditors.

So far this year, the Brazilian real is down 19 percent (external debt of $545 billion), the Russian ruble is down 17 percent (external debt of $451 billion), the Indian rupee is down 9 percent (external debt of $483 billion), the Chinese yuan is down 6.5 percent (external debt of $1.6 trillion), and the South African rand is down 14 percent (external debt of $144 billion, all of which will be reneged on as the country goes full-Zimbabwe).

These countries, the BRICS, were the darlings of this credit cycle. With the Turkish situation, the emerging-market bank jog is turning into a run. Asia will follow, with $2.1 trillion in dollar debt, not counting China.

The end of August has brought some market respite, due to maneuvering by the Turkish banking authorities: They suspended mark-to-market accounting for capital adequacy ratios, encouraged banks to extend maturities, and limited banks’ ability to lend lira to offshore funds for the purpose of shorting it.

The pause in the panic will be limited. Turkey used its foreign credit to finance the construction of shopping malls and office towers, and overcapacity makes the true value of this collateral much lower than what is carried on bank balance sheets. Speculators help accelerate a collapse—the market, left to its own devices, will always swiftly liquidate malinvestment—neutering speculators can merely prolong the agony.

First Victim

It is falling cash flows that ultimately pop a bubble. The emerging-market rout may have already claimed its first financial victim. On July 31, the Zurich-based GAM Investments gated redemptions of a 9.5 billion euro bond fund after suspending the manager because “Mr. Haywood may have failed, in our judgment, to conduct or evidence sufficient due diligence on some of the investments that were made, or make accessible internal records of documents relating to these.”

GAM assures its frozen clients: “To date, we have not concluded that there are any inaccuracies in the current NAVs of the relevant funds.”

The problem is that more than 10 percent of the capital tried to redeem: “The funds have the necessary liquidity to serve the redemption requests we have received, but such actions would lead to a disproportional shift in their portfolio composition, which could compromise the interests of remaining investors.”

According to the Financial Times: “The ARBF strategies followed a so-called ‘go anywhere’ approach, which gave portfolio managers freedom to choose securities from a wide range of structures and regions. The funds’ annual report includes more than 150 pages dedicated to listing the assets they invest in, which vary from treasuries, corporate bonds and emerging market debt to more exotic assets such as mortgage-backed securities, collateralized loan obligations, and credit default swaps.”

Let’s recall how a model bank functions: It takes in demand deposits, keeps a small portion as actual cash reserves at the Fed, buys some Treasury bonds (which it gets to count as reserves), and loans the rest out at term, setting in motion the credit cycle described above. When depositors start asking for their money back, the reserves can be paid out immediately, but the remaining depositors get stuck with the long-term, illiquid assets.

A run accelerates until the government suspends withdrawals, and the bank is required to liquidate its assets and distribute the recoveries, if any, to the depositors over time. In other words, this unconstrained bond fund isn’t a fund at all but an unregulated, maturity transforming bank. Note the cleverly composed claim that there are no inaccuracies “in the current NAVs.”

What is current? Like a bank, as long as no one tries to leave, the fund can continue the fiction that its assets have value. Anyone invested in other “unconstrained” bond funds would be a fool not to start moving slowly toward the exit.

The Keynesian framework, completely dominant since 1922, would call for money printing now, before the problems get worse, before countries besides Turkey are forced into capital controls, before other bond funds and ETFs need to gate their investors. But the Fed has recently reinforced its tightening policy—it thinks it can enforce a new equilibrium, to keep asset prices at a permanently high plateau. Combined with emerging market liquidation, Fed tightening will instead create a liquidity black hole.

Market Panic

It is in the nature of market panics that they accelerate. The Fed must respond soon or watch the whole post-2008 recovery crumble. If it does, there is a chance the Fed can play the same game it has played since 1980, printing up another round of the credit cycle.

If the Fed does not respond in time or forcefully enough, the world will soon experience a credit contraction far greater than the 1930s. Austrian theory tells us that a central bank can always delay a credit collapse, but only at the cost of making it worse.

Dan Oliver is the principal at gold-mining fund Myrmikan Capital.
Views expressed in this article are opinions of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of The Epoch Times.
Dan Oliver is the principal at gold mining fund Myrmikan Capital.
Related Topics